Wednesday, December 26, 2012

Reading Keynes part 3

In my previous post in this series I described some thoughts that came from reading book III of Keynes's General Theory. Before moving on to discussing subsequent books, I'd like to make some notes regarding the simple model I discussed in that post.

The first note regards how a lack of consumer spending (in the absence of saving and investment) could drive an economy to disaster. A step in the argument was that employees who feared for their jobs will cut their consumer spending. This is plausible, but there are really two types of such spending. The one that can be most readily cut is the spending on luxuries, but spending on essentials, such as food, clothing, rent and repairs cannot be cut below a certain level. This enforced minimal level of consumption can stop a descent into complete economic collapse, but the word 'disaster' is still applicable as this bottomed-out economy will doubtless have high unemployment and a class of the employed that are living on the breadline.

My second note on the last post concerns the statement at the end on how effectively the 1% can syphon away the wealth of the 99%. This jars with the fact that the 1% own the companies that pay the wage bill of the 99%, and that they are therefore reliant on the consumers (the 99%) recycling the money back to them by spending and/or saving. I think the answer here is two-fold. A minority of companies do successfully syphon money to themselves (e.g. Apple) but it's at the expense of their competitors (e.g. Microsoft) not their customers. But I was really meaning sums of money summed up across the whole economy, and I believe that aggregate syphoning from consumers isn't significant, and that it can actually occur towards the poorer 99%. However, it is clear that the 1% start off with disproportionate ownership of wealth, including the capital to generate and control it, and they use that control to make sure they continue to own their unfair share.

Book IV of The General Theory is entitled The inducement to invest and its first of eight chapters is called The marginal efficiency of capital. In very loose terms, the marginal efficiency of capital is to capital what interest is to money (despite the popular misconception, capital is not synonymous with money). If we give money to another party, we can expect them to pay us a sum of money over time  - the interest - for allowing them to hold and use the money. Likewise, if we invest in purchasing some capital equipment, say machines for making mobile phones in a factory, then we will expect our ownership of those machines to bring us a net income over time from the sale of produced goods. Keynes makes a rigorous definition of the marginal efficiency of capital so he can go on to compare such income with interest rates. The main conceptual difference between the two is that for the latter the owner of the money is not directly concerned with how the asset (i.e. the money) is used to generate a return.

Much of the subsequent chapters are concerned with discussing the interplay between the marginal efficiency of capital and interest rates. If interest rates are low then there is a greater incentive to invest in purchasing capital assets and expect a return from them, and vice versa for high interest rates. But, of course, it is not so simple. There are psychological factors at work. How do people perceive the future? If there is optimism that consumer spending will remain strong, then investment in capital will be more attractive. But if not, people may have a preference for liquidity and be less inclined to lock up money in more difficult to release capital equipment, even if interest rates are not very high.

Keynes discusses what sets money apart from other repositories of wealth and makes the point that interest is not actually unique to money. One example that occurred to me was carrots. A crop of carrots is perishable, unlike money, but a given number of carrots can be planted and grown - that is "invested" - so that year-on-year, assuming you didn't sell them, you would add to the total number of carrots in your possession (even though these wouldn't be the same carrots). You could quite legitimately call the extra number of carrots each year your interest. If you instead, as most farmers do, sold those carrots to receive a return in terms of money then that return would feed into your calculation of your marginal efficiency of capital (along with the initial stock of carrots, land, machinery etc).

The carrot example illustrates a couple of points, most obviously that money is preferential to carrots for holding wealth because it doesn't necessarily incur land, labour and storage costs. But it also demonstrates what Keynes calls "own-interest", i.e. you can define the interest rate of carrots in terms of carrots. This helps explain what he means in this key quote from Chapter 17 Section III:
No further increase in the rate of investment is possible when the greatest amongst the own-rates of own-interest of all available assets is equal to the greatest amongst the marginal efficiencies of all assets, measured in terms of the asset whose own-rate of own-interest is greatest.

He argues that the thing with the greatest own-rate of own-interest is money. So, in plainer English, he is saying that people will put their wealth into a form that they see as most likely to increase their wealth. The convoluted digression into interest defined in terms of other assets (such as carrots) strikes me as possibly a distracting abstraction, but it shows the rigour that Keynes wished to apply to his arguments.

To return to the key point, the halting of investment caused by a high money rate of interest can (and usually does) stop an economy proceeding to full employment. To put it more starkly: even if companies are wanting to find a way to increase profits, and even if willing and able unemployed workers are wanting employment, the economy might not be able to respond because of a blockage caused by a shortage of the very thing that is supposed to facilitate the economy: money. Keynes highlights this absurdity in his delightfully idiosyncratic style:
Unemployment develops...because people want the moon;- men cannot be employed when the object of desire (i.e. money) is something which cannot be produced and the demand for which cannot readily be choked off. There is no remedy but to persuade the public that green cheese is practically the same thing and to have a green cheese factory (i.e. a central bank) under public control.
He goes on to highlight the folly of attempting to anchor the value of money against a rare substance extracted from the Earth:
It is interesting to notice that the characteristic which has been traditionally supposed to render gold especially suitable for use as the standard of value, namely, its inelasticity of supply, turns out to be precisely the characteristic which is at the bottom of the trouble.
In other words, if you tie money to something that appears to have tangible value, then you actually make the situation worse because you lose all control over the supply of money to the economy and are then completely helpless in dealing with a money shortage.

But, putting gold standards, interest rates and capital aside, the problem is very simple: we have become too preoccupied with money itself, to the extent it distracts us from the essentials of the production it is supposed to facilitate, namely, securing food, shelter, employment and health.

Sunday, November 18, 2012

Fesenjan

Fesenjun - pestle & mortar and saffron to the left.
When I was a wee boy, probably about the age my son is now (7), I remember being confronted by a dish that my aunt had made at her home in London. "That's mud, isn't it?" I said, without meaning to be funny, but everyone laughed and they still laugh about it. The mud was an ancient dish from Iran called Fesenjan. It was by far the most delicious mud I had ever tasted.

I don't recall eating Fesenjan again until a few years ago when I spotted it on the menu of an excellent restaurant called Paradise in Glasgow. That was very different from the one my aunt had made, much more sweet and sour, so much so that I imagine that it would over-challenge too many people's palettes. Sadly it probably did, as it doesn't appear on their menu any more.

Some months back I started cooking recipes I found in a Persian cookbook my wife had bought on a trip to California (where there are many Iranians). At first I didn't spot the recipe for Fesenjan, but when I did I had a go at cooking it. The first try was good, but not quite as dramatic and intense as I had wanted, so I tried again and ended up with the recipe I described below. I've cooked it for quite a few friends now and it seems to go down very well and it really is quite different from anything they've tried before.

Fesenjan is really made distinctive by the combination of walnuts and pomegranate. It is most commonly served with chicken, but duck, beef or vegetables can all be substituted. I don't recall what my aunt put in it, but there were no large lumps of meat, so I wonder if she used minced beef or even lamb. I intend to experiment with that for the true muddy consistency.

Fesejan - serves 6
2 finely sliced medium onions
1kg of chicken, legs and thighs preferred
1 litre of pomegranate juice
300g of walnuts, ground in food processor
1 tsp saffron, ground in a pestle and mortar
1 butternut squash cut into 1 inch cubes
1 tbsp of muscavado sugar
juice of one lime or lemon
some pomegranate seeds and some unground walnuts for garnish

1. In a large deep-sided pot, fry the onion in a few tablespoons of olive oil, and add the chicken and butternut squash after a few minutes. After a few more minutes of stir frying, turn the heat down and cover it while you prepare the sauce.
2. Put the ground walnuts in a bowl with the pomegranate juice and lime or lemon juice and sugar.
3. Dissolve the saffron in a tablespoon or two of hot water (as much as it will dissolve) and pour into the bowl and mix it.
4. Pour the contents of the bowl into the pan with the onion, squash and chicken.
5. Cook on a low heat, uncovered for 2 hours. Stir every 15 minutes or so to avoid the walnuts burning. The sauce should reduce and thicken quite a bit, but if you like it a bit more runny and less intense in flavour, you can put a lid on it for some of the time.
6. Garnish with pomegranate seeds and unground walnuts and serve with rice.

Wednesday, November 14, 2012

Reading Keynes part 2

I've now completed reading book III of The General Theory by John Maynard Keynes. I previously wrote about my thoughts on books I and II. The title of book III is "The propensity to consume" and it is composed of three chapters.

Probably the most important statement made in this part is in Chapter 3, section II, paragraph 2:
 

Thus, to justify any given amount of employment there must be an amount of current investment sufficient to absorb the excess of total output over what the community chooses to consume when employment is at a given level.

Out of context the meaning may not be clear, so I'll try and explain in my own words, using a very simple model of my own devising.

Consider a simple, closed economy which comprises a number of companies and a community of people - the consumers - who will buy products from those companies. The economy is closed in the sense that it does no trade with any other companies or consumers elsewhere, i.e. there are no imports or exports. Let's also suppose there is no taxation or spending by a government.

So each one of the consumers are either employed by a company or else they are unemployed and have zero income (the government doesn't spend, so there is no welfare state). The ones who are employed receive a monthly wage from their company. Let's add up all the wages across this community and call it W. Also, each consumer will spend a certain amount each month. Let's add up all that is spent and call it C.

Each company will have an income, and if we add up the income from selling to consumers across all companies we must find that it comes to C - the total the consumers have spent. One company can sell to another company and so we can add up the business-to-business income across all companies and call it B.

The costs of each company will be the amount it pays out in wages plus the amount it spends on buying from other companies. Adding up wages across all companies must give us W. Because this is a closed economy, the total spent on companies buying products must be B.

So the total income of all companies is C+B and their total costs are W+B. The total profit across all companies is therefore C-W (the Bs cancel out).

And you may have spotted the problem with this simple economy. People will generally not spend more than they earn (and even if they do, they can not do so indefinitely). This means that the total amount spent on buying products from companies C will have to be less than the total wage bill W, or, in other words, the companies in this economy must make an overall loss of W-C. Of course, there will be winners and losers - profitable companies and loss-making companies - but overall companies are loss making in this economy.

A company that finds it is making a loss will try to drive down its costs. It can do this by reducing what it pays to other companies, and it will probably also reduce its wage bill, either by cutting wages or by firing employees. The overall result will of course be to drive down B and W, though B has no impact on the overall profitability of companies. But, as we argued above, C cannot be greater than W, so if W is decreased, C will decrease too. In fact, employees who are starting to fear for their jobs are likely to start saving and so the total amount they spend C will probably fall by even more than W and so the overall loss W-C may even increase. In any event though, W will remain greater than C.

This effect is an example of positive feedback in that the fact that W is greater than C will cause companies to act in a way that will cause W-C to increase. In this way, without any other stabilising factors, the economy will collapse: all companies will go bust and everyone will become unemployed.

And this is where the quote from Keynes above becomes relevant. To stop this happening, the companies, as a whole, need to receive monies from another source to offset the loss they collectively make, i.e. W-C. This extra source of monies Keynes calls "investment". And where does it come from? Well, in this simple economy it can only come from what the consumers don't spend on goods. Instead they either use their savings to buy shares in a company or save the money by putting it in banks that then invest or lend the money to the companies. And, of course, this excess of consumers income over spending is exactly equal to W-C, which means this economy can be made stable in the sense that companies can break even overall and so the level of employment can be sustained.

The essential point that Keynes is making here is that investments and savings in an economy are necessarily equal. I had previously only thought of investment as being necessary for companies that want to grow or establish themselves as start-ups. Although that's true, I can now see that continued investment is a necessity to sustain a stable economy because of the gap between C and W.

The other point which Keynes makes is that an economy that has reached a stable equilibrium may have done so at less than full employment. It may well be, and in fact generally is the case, that the willingness to invest and the propensity to consume are not sufficient to motivate companies to increase their production and take on more employees. The unemployed who have zero income (there is no welfare state in my model) would clearly prefer to work, but the companies will not employ them because they cannot see how this would maintain or increase their profits.  This conclusion, that an economy can be stable at less than full employment, distinguishes Keynes's theory from that of classical economics (at least of his own time, but I bet there are still many who do not get this point today). 

There are a number of other interesting implications that can be drawn from this simple model. One is to consider what happens if hoarding rather than saving occurs in the economy. For example, an old miser who distrusts banks, stuffs all excess money under a mattress. Likewise, a bank that takes deposits but refuses to lend is doing much the same thing. The result in both cases is that money enters a stagnant pool and the economy as a whole will suffer because it is deprived of investment. If money could be released from that stagnant pool, then employment could rise because companies could access a new potential source of revenue. Of course, in my simple model there is no government to spend, but in reality, government spending can achieve the same result in raising employment.

But, if there's one lesson to take away from this simple model, it is that "one person's spending is another's income", or more specifically, "consumer spending is company revenue". Companies as a whole are completely beholden to their consumers. If consumers do not part with their money to buy products, then it is their savings transformed into investments which keeps the companies in business. This raises an interesting question: how does this fit with the current situation in which the richest 1% of the population, who presumably own companies, are often supposed to be syphoning wealth from the 99%? I'm still pondering this question, but will save my attempts at an answer for a future blog post.

Tuesday, October 16, 2012

Reading Keynes part 1

It was my fortieth birthday recently and I was glad to be presented with many books. Amongst them, courtesy of my father, were The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith and The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money by John Maynard Keynes. I decided to start reading the latter book first. This is the first in a series of posts in which I'll try and explain what I've got out of the experience.

First off, I'm not an economist by training, but the problems with economies around the world in recent years have kindled my interest, especially when I began to appreciate that so-called "Keynesian" solutions, as described by the likes of Paul Krugman, seemed to not only stand up to skeptical, rational scrutiny but also had a very solid basis in historical precedent. Before going further, the very first thing I learned is that Keynes is pronounced canes, not keens.

Not being an economist of the early 20th century makes reading Keynes's classic book a bit of a challenge. My first stumble was when I encountered the word "disutility". I tried and failed to understand it from the context and a search of the web kept leading back to extracts from the book itself. It turned out that "utility" is a term in economics used to quantify human satisfaction and that the word "disutility" was either peculiar to Keynes himself, or else is now arcane. The term appears in the context of Keynes disputing the received economist wisdom of his time that workers settle for a real-wage (i.e. in real terms, not in terms of an amount of money) that is just sufficient to make their employed state of greater utility (or lesser disutility) than their unemployed state. If you are struggling with that last sentence, then you have a sense of what it feels like to read Keynes's book.

The point is valid though. An employee will immediately seek redress with their employer if forced to take a pay cut, i.e. the money-wage is reduced, but may not even notice if the real-wage is reduced, say, because prices of everyday items have increased. Even if noticed, the employer is unlikely to see rebargaining the wage as their problem; they too may be faced with increased business costs due to increased prices. This situation is playing out just now across Europe: in Spain and Greece people are understandably furious at having to take money-wage cuts (or else be made unemployed) to solve economic problems that were not of their creation. Meanwhile, outside the land of the Euro, in Iceland, most people implicitly accepted real-wage cuts when the Icelandic currency was devalued.

The next piece of received wisdom at which Keynes takes aim is the notion that "Supply creates its own demand". That strikes me as immediately strange, but nevertheless there are still people who believe it today. One implication of it is that there should be no involuntary unemployment, on the basis that everyone who wishes to work can do, because when they produce something, there will be a demand from someone, somewhere to buy it. This seems so obviously absurd that you may wonder why it would need refuted, either in 1936 by Keynes, or by anyone today. Of course, the absurdity of it is not often as plainly stated as this, but it is implicit in much economic wrong-thinking. In fact, as Keynes sets out, if you believe in "supply creates its own demand" or one of many equivalent variants of that statement then you are actually adopting an economic model that assumes there is no real barrier to full employment. In boom times that might not be so bad a model, but during a depression, like the current one, it's simply the wrong model to adopt. To use an analogy: if a car fails to start, no amount of tinkering with the engine will help if you've incorrectly assumed that it has sufficient fuel in the tank.

But, that said, after only having read books I and II of Keynes' classic text, I have not yet encountered anything else that you would recognise as "Keynesian", e.g. that governments should spend their way out of a recession. Instead, Keynes has merely sketched his ideas in broad brush and then painstakingly set out a series of definitions of net income, investment, saving and something called "user cost" (akin to depreciation, except that no cost is incurred if equipment is idle) so that he can go on to describe his theory in subsequent books. In other words, he found the economic descriptions of his own time too vague and imprecise to formulate his theory and so invented his own.

I am not one who is prone to hero-worship and I certainly do not worship Keynes nor accept his ideas without question. But it is clear Keynes was a very intelligent person and, more importantly, an independent-minded individual. Don't take my word for it - have read (or listen) to what philospher John Gray had to say about him.

Thursday, October 4, 2012

Lucentis - a poke in the eye

Yesterday I received my first eye injection to treat the condition that has developed with the retina in my left eye. I can't say I relished the prospect of someone sticking a needle in my eye and squirting liquid into it, but then again, I was nowhere near as aghast or horrified as the people I told about it - one person said "don't tell my husband, he'll throw up on you!".

No doubt, the ghoulish reader will want me to get straight to the bit where I describe the crazed doctor, laughing maniacally, stabbing me in the eye causing me to convulse and scream in agony. Well, there you go, I've just done it. Non-ghoulish readers, read on...

In the week since I'd been diagnosed, the distortion had spread across my retina so that it now affects the centre of my vision. This perturbed me enough so that I returned to the hospital and successfully (and politely) argued with the medics to get the treatment brought forward by a week. If the damage was likely to be permanent, it was paramount to get treatment as soon as I could.

I arrived at the eye clinic at 8.45am on a Tuesday morning for my injection, but was kept waiting for an hour. It's beyond me how you can be an hour behind at the start of the day, but the lumbering, administration-heavy machine that is the NHS is like that. That said, in my experiences, and as this story will demonstrate, the care that machine facilitates, to every citizen of the UK, regardless of income or means, is very definitely not broken.

My fellow eye-patients probably had an average age of well above seventy, and these veterans of the eye clinic, and life in general, sat there looking relaxed and possibly slightly bored. I have to marvel at the stoicism of elderly Glaswegians. If these old codgers and codgerinas could stick it, so could I.

The substance to be injected into my eye is called Ranibizumab, though it is more commonly known by its brand name Lucentis. It is derived from an antibody found in mice and inhibits the growth of blood vessels which may leak fluid into the eye, causing the edema (swelling) that is distorting my retina. Apparently Lucentis costs over $1000 per dose, whereas there exist alternatives priced at $40 per dose that are claimed to be as effective. I suspect massive profiteering is going on here and plan to investigate further.

Anyway, after 45 minutes in the large, main waiting room, and 15 minutes sat in a chair in a corridor, I was called into the small room. There was a reclining, padded chair, much like one you'd find in a dentist's surgery, a table and a cabinet stuffed with packets of medical equipment. It was soon apparent who the doctor was, as he swept around the room, talking in a clear, confident voice, not a hint of doubt coming into anything he said. There was also a specialist nurse and he too seemed sure of what he was doing, but spoke less and was more garbled. And there was another nurse who, after than showing me into the room, seemed to be waiting quietly in the corner.

I lay down on the chair and it whirred and reclined me. I asked the doctor a few questions about my condition and he gave me clear, matter-of-fact answers. Apparently, some people thought eating leafy greens helped this condition and, he said, it was always good to be trying things that made you think you were helping yourself. After I said I wasn't a smoker, he spoke a bit about how bad smoking was for macular edema and health in general.

Through all of this conversation, he and the specialist nurse were buzzing about me, swabbing my eye, preparing the eye and giving me a few anesthetic drops. I think this went on for about ten minutes and the chat not only informed me but helped keep me distracted. Since I wasn't wearing my glasses I couldn't really see much, but I was thinking "is the needle coming now?" They placed something like a large plaster over my eye and peeled a layer away to reveal a transparent layer. I think this was to hold my eye in place with the eyelid clamped back, but I was already doing my level best to keep my eyes still. I suspected the moment was coming when the nurse took my hand and began to squeeze and stroke it gently. Simultaneously, the doctor who was hovering around behind me and to my left began to move something towards my eye. Being so myopic I couldn't see it, which was probably a good thing, and then there was a strange sensation - not pain, more like a dull ache. A giant floater appeared in my eye and I mentioned it. The doctor apologised, saying that a wee bit of air had got in, but it should be harmless and would sink to the top of my vision when I stood up (the image on the retina is inverted, the brain reverts for you).

So that was it. I really couldn't fault the way it was done: friendly, professional and caring. If I was a macho man, I might have rejected the nurse's hand-holding, but I'm not and it helped. She was doing more than a job, she was caring about her job and the human before her. I could easily imagine a bean-counter, administrator saying "we don't need two nurses in the Lucentis clinic", but if they did, someone with more sense prevailed.

For the rest of the day, it felt like there was something in my eye and so I was blinking a lot and it was very teary. I suspect that the "something" in my eye was a little rough spot on my eyeball where the needle went in and that was irritating my eyelid. The eye was a little red, but other than that and a slightly dull ache around my eye, I experienced no other untoward symptoms.

The distortion in my left eye has got no better or worse in the last week or so, but it is quite possible that it stabilised by itself before the injection.  My brain is doing a better job at compensating: unless I consciously look for it, the distortion isn't apparent to me most of the time. My binocular vision is still a little compromised as my brain struggles to reconcile the different images coming from my left and right eyes, but I think it's improving too. I try to give it a helping hand by increasing font sizes on the computer, for which the zoom function in my web browser (firefox) comes in very handy. So far, so good.

But, I'm remarkably lucky. Does every human on Earth get such treatment? Would I have got it 100 years ago in this country, without the NHS? No. I'm very, very grateful and I hope that one day everyone can expect at least this level of heath care.

Saturday, September 8, 2012

Real retinal resolution

Sometimes you notice a small thing that turns out to have much larger implications. So it happened last week. I noticed that the lines along the top of a spreadsheet seemed to bend, just slightly and only for a fraction of a second as I shifted my gaze - but I saw it. I thought at first it was some problem with my monitor, but when I saw it happen on another computer, I knew it was me and not the machine that was faulty.

I am very short sighted and this results in the retina being stretched and made very thin and prone to spontaneous damage. The retina is the surface at the back of your eye that has many receptors that detect light. Each receptor feeds pulses to your optic nerve that allow the brain to construct an image that you see, well, that you think you see (it's a long story). It didn't take me long to realise that the retina in my left eye was faulty and I wasted no time in making an appointment at the optician. This was Friday.

On Saturday morning I saw the optometrist and she was extremely diligent and tested my eyes and photographed my retina but could find nothing wrong. She then arranged to have a 3D scan performed to see if the damage was below the retinal surface, but that too was inconclusive. We both agreed that whatever had happened to my eye, it was not deteriorating, so she arranged an  appointment at the hospital at 10am on Monday, but warned me to go to A&E if the condition changed over the weekend.

On Monday I spent the day having the same tests again and was given a thorough examination by a young doctor. She too was unable to identify the problem either by direct examination or from the results of any of the scans. She called in the consultant and he spotted a small hint on one of the scans and sent me off for a dye test. This test involves the injection of a yellow dye (fluoroscein) into the veins so that it will travel through your whole body; any disturbed or exposed blood vessels in the retina will give off a strong glow. I was warned that the dye would give me the appearance of a Homer Simpson, but it didn't give me more than a mild tan, though it did turn my urine a spectacular fluorescent yellow.

The dye-test showed the problem - I had a macular edema. The macula is the part of the eye that is most densely covered in receptors and it is what we rely on for detail in the centre of our vision. We rely on it for reading and perceiving fine detail in facial recognition. Edema means swelling - in my case a membrane at the back of my retina had ruptured causing liquid to enter an area just below the retinal surface. The consequence of this is that receptors in my eye have been re-arranged and possibly damaged.

The consultant explained all this to me and to be honest I was not at all alarmed. I already knew that my retina was damaged and, if anything, was reassured to have the details of it recognised and explained to me by an expert. I guessed that the damage was permanent but also guessed that, in time, my brain would be able to cope with this disruption, perhaps even learn the new locations of the remaining and undamaged receptors. The consultant confirmed this to me. He also assured me that there was a viable treatment that could prevent further deterioration, though this involved a series of injections into the eyeball and that the eye would need close attention for years to come.

An idea of the view through my left eye if I'm looking at the word "just".
For now, I need to live with a distortion in my left eye. In some circumstances, e.g. when outside or just looking around a room or driving, it is barely noticeable. At most I'll notice a brief kink in a window frame or a bend in a lamp post, but only fleetingly. If I use only my left (damaged) eye to read, then I can focus on a word with little distortion, but two or three words to the right do appear distorted, though legible. Using both eyes together is better, but I can feel the extra strain on my brain and eyes of having to reconcile two different images. But, in time, I'm sure my brain will rewire itself.

What I see when I blink, with added starship.
The distortion itself is always in the same place, a little to right and above my centre of vision. It is shaped like a flower and resembles five or so overlapping circles. Inside this shape my vision is distorted. I was pleased the other day that when I placed the Moon inside it (which was actually quite tricky) that I could still see it, although it was not round, nor could I see much in the way of features on it. The size of distortion is about half the area of my clenched fist held at arms length, so approximately 5 degrees across its longest part. If I close my eyes for a few seconds and then open them I can clearly see the outline of it, but just for a moment. If I blink rapidly I can see it as a blob, much like the blob left after you have viewed a bright object such as the Sun. Sometimes it reminds me of a poor Star Trek special effect, minus the Enterprise.

I can live with this level of distortion, but I do fear it deteriorating and spreading to cloud my entire vision in that eye. If, as is possible, a problem develops with my right eye then my visual acuity could deteriorate to the point where I can no longer read, but I won't go completely blind. Although the cause is different, the effects are not unlike the macular degeneration experienced in older people. I have to face up to the fact that significant loss of my eyesight is likely to occur as I age and that what some people face in their late seventies or eighties has started (just) before I reach 40.

This prospect is causing me some anxiety and I can feel a black cloud hovering behind me, dampening my ambitions and tempting me to retreat, dwell and introspect. To give into that leads to depression, so my aim is to reaffirm my ambitions and keep going regardless. I will take the treatment on offer, I will have faith that although my eyesight is failing, that it will do so in a stable way and that, at least for now, my brain can adapt. And, if things get so bad that brain cannot compensate then I will turn to computers and technology for help and rely more on my ears, for example by using audio books. But at the same time I must acknowledge this new limitation.

I feel fortunate that my interests are varied enough that the limitation will not dampen my enthusiasm for life. I am even more fortunate that I have a loving and supportive family around me and some very good friends. In fact, it has already occurred to me that limitation is not always a bad thing - I am prone to trying to do too much at once and so frustrate my ambitions in any one endeavour. Also, wherever I go, and wherever I look, I am now always accompanied by a colourful little amoeba-like flower when I blink, and, for reasons I don't quite understand myself, I actually feel some affection for the little thing.

Monday, August 6, 2012

Owncloud

Go into the "cloud", use the "cloud", harness the power of the "cloud", "cloud" computing, "cloud" this, "cloud" that... blah blah blah. Of course, the word has some meaning, but it has been so abused, misused and used to confuse that I now find it irksome. But there are more tangible problems with the ideas behind it. (I'll stop using "scare" quotes now.)

The obvious problem with storing your data in the cloud is that you don't know where it is or who can see it. Another problem is that if you use software that is in the cloud, for example gmail, then you have zero control over changes to that software. If google decides to update gmail, you will be forced to switch to the new version at some point whether you want to or not.

I could live - and do live - with these and other drawbacks of the cloud, but there is one other problem that troubles me more. I rely on google for mail, contacts, calendar, documents, web sites, my phone, this blog... Although I have no particular problem with Google at the moment, it does not sit well with me to have so many eggs in one monopolist's basket.

So when I first came across ownCloud, I was immediately attracted to the idea. ownCloud is software you can install on your own webserver and you can control how your data is stored and accessed and since the software is Free and Open Source (under the AGPL license), you have as much control over it as you could wish for.

Of course, not everyone has the time, inclination, knowledge or money to run their own web server, but then perhaps there is a web-skilled friend you might trust, or you could choose to use a commercial provider who is offering a pre-installed set up for you. The project has a company (owncloud.com) that lives in symbiosis with the open source community (owncloud.org).

So far I've tried out the file sharing, music, calendar, contacts and gallery aspects of owncloud and experimented accessing it from my android phone. My server is in my house running on a low-power linutop 2. It's not fast, but fast enough for my purposes just now. I will write another post with more technical aspects.

Once I've finished a bit more fettling, perhaps I will invite some friends into my ownCloud, but will they trust me with their precious data?

Sunday, July 1, 2012

Raspberry pi - beta lego

My RPi now has a new home - a lego case. I tried to convince my 7 year old son to build it, but he felt playing minecraft and ace of spaces on the computer was more important, so I rummaged through his lego collection and constructed what you see below.

OK, so it's not going to win any prizes, but it does have windows. No, not microsoft windows, but windows through which you can see its LEDs. Just look at the cosy glow from its rear window. (I've decided that the ethernet cable gets plugged up its arse and its power goes in its mouth.)


I've also installed a new operating system, the beta of Debian wheezy for the RPi, and it seems to work just fine. I've fed back one minor problem I had (to do with he config tool) to the developer via github and I hope to contribute a bit more in the future.

My next task was to set up ssh access, which was easily done with this command:

  sudo service ssh start

and to make sure this happens after every boot, I issued this command:

  sudo insserv ssh

Of course, this isn't much use if you don't know the IP number, so to set a static IP I just had to edit /etc/network.interfaces to read:

  auto lo

  iface lo inet loopback
  iface eth0 inet static
  address 192.168.1.23
  netmask 255.255.255.0
  gateway 192.168.1.1

When I'm ssh'ing into it, I don't type in 192.168.1.23 every time, instead I gave this IP the identity of "summerston" on my other computers (editing /etc/hosts on linux) in keeping with my policy of naming my computers after defunct Glasgow train stations (Summerston train station is actually open, but the original station from which it gets its name, but which was several miles away, has been closed for about forty years).

The last thing I set up was a VNC server so I could access the GUI desktop from my laptop, this was just two commands. The first installed the necessary software:

  sudo apt-get install tightvncserver

and the second started the server:

  vncserver :1

I was then able to access the desktop from my laptop using KDE's VNC client called KRDC and also my phone using a VNC app. It looked just like this:

Wednesday, June 27, 2012

Raspberry pi - first steps

After waiting a couple of months, my raspberry pi finally arrived the other day. For those of you that don't know, it is a ludicrously cheap ($35 or £25) computer that is sold as a bare board with a few connectors on it. In contrast to the out-of-the-box shininess that is now the raging fashion, this wee beastie is minimal and challenges you to learn something about it, and about computers in general. In fact, that's exactly why the raspberry pi came into being.

The tiny thing on top of the standard PC case in this photo is my raspberry pi. There are only two cables plugged in here: the ethernet cable at the back and the power cable (standard USB phone charging cable) at the front. You can also just make out the SD card which is slotted in the same side as the power cable. This serves as its disk drive.
My first task after unboxing my new, little friend was to write the operating system to the SD card. This was simple enough, I downloaded the Debian linux image from the raspberry pi website, verified the file's integrity by its sha1 sum using this command

  sha1sum debian6-19-04-2012.img

stuck the SD in my laptop (running slackware linux 13.37) and ran
 
  dd bs=1M if=debian6-19-04-2012.img of=/dev/sdb

(first checking that the SD card was /dev/sdb - much badness can occur if you get that wrong!). I then put the card in raspberry pi, plugged it into my TV using the HDMI cable, plugged in a USB wireless keyboard and mouse and then... drum roll... plugged it into the power and... more drum roll... some LEDs flashed but nothing appeared on the TV. It turned out that the TV had to be on and set to HDMI before I turned on the pi and once I did that... yet another drum roll... it worked! Text scrolled by and the little raspberry pi logo sat at the top left of the screen, looking cute and somehow content.

I was then able to start X windows with the LXDE desktop by issuing the command 'startx' and soon I had a giant logo emblazoned on my 32" TV. After some fiddling around loading the sound module I got the sound working and was able to listen to the short demo piece of music that comes with the music player. The software to get the pi's hardware doing its stuff is still in development and the sound is apparently quite buggy at present. My next task will probably be to get beta testing the next version of the Debian OS for the pi.

So, what am I going to do with it? I don't yet know exactly what I'll do with it, except probably what any child would do with a new toy: play with it.


Saturday, April 28, 2012

Science and family

Last Saturday I helped out a science fair at my son's school called Science Rocks. It was a fantastic event and I thoroughly enjoyed it and it's clear that it entertained, educated and inspired all who attended. So much so, that I spent my Sunday afternoon searching  a nearby park (Dawsholm Park) for insects with my son and friends who were all fired up as entomologists.

I had the pleasure of giving planetarium shows using Glasgow University's inflatable Starlab planetarium. I was ably assisted by son who operated its controls - no mean feat for a 7 year old surrounded by people, lots of noise and in the dark.


I'd like to share something with you which has been bouncing around in my mind this last week. Almost 50 years ago, a young woman came over from Iran. She spoke very little English but was determined to spend a few years in the UK to further her career in nuclear physics. She not only ended up with a PhD, but also found a husband, settled in Bearsden, Glasgow and secured a research job working on Glasgow University's linear accelerator. When she became pregnant she was forced to stop working around radiation and went on early maternity leave to have her baby. That baby was me. (Yes, the radiation exposure probably does answer a lot of your questions about me.)

Unfortunately, the concept of maternity leave was not well established back then, especially in the very male-dominated profession of academic science and so my mother was not able to resume her scientific career, but she did, after much perseverance, manage to return to work at Glasgow University in computing. Although disappointed in this, she was a fantastic and devoted mother and gave my sister and I the best start in life one could wish for. I know she was pleased that my sister and I went on to have careers in science and engineering and particularly that my sister was able to have two children without much detriment to her career.

My mother died a year and a day before the science fair, and that has been on my mind quite a bit this week. But I'm absolutely sure she would've loved it and been delighted to see such a great science fair being run by a group of mothers, with a little help from a few dads.